Enforcing the medical loss ratio (MLR) provision of the Health Reform law means that health insurers must spend 80% to 85% of premiums on medical care. In my November 2010 post regarding MLRs, I noted that preliminary CMS regulations deemed that cost control efforts would not count as “medical care” – even those activities designed to detect inappropriate services .
MLR is a basic ratio. The premium (money the health insurer is paid) is the denominator and medical care (claims, case management etc.) is the numerator. Under the law, administrative activities are not counted in the numerator. As such, efforts to reduce inappropriate childhood tube insertions or unnecessary coronary artery bypass graft (CABG) surgeries are counted against the insurer in the calculation of MLR. These activities, instead, are counted in the “other non-claims costs” category.
From a regulator’s point of view, this makes sense. How would a state insurance department be able to sort out whether an activity was a) restricting access to appropriate care to profit or b) controlling inappropriate services by profit-seeking providers?
Unfortunately, by classifying all direct medical services as “value to the consumer,” the law fails to recognize what the Dartmouth Atlas of Health Care research has been telling us for decades: more healthcare is not necessarily good healthcare. The failure to distinguish necessary medical care from inappropriate care makes the MLR provision wholly misguided.
The MLR floor is an understandable reaction to the abuses by some health insurers who have blatantly (or incompetently) restricted access to needed care to fatten their coffers. With the new MLR law, policymakers hope that insurers: 1) increase medical care costs, or 2) decrease administrative expenses (including marketing costs and profits).
Instead what will probably happen is that health insurers will increase premiums (while keeping administrative costs the same). This will make the MLR floor easier to obtain. They could also lobby to categorize some administrative costs (call centers, etc.) as medical care. Lobbyists are trying to convince CMS of this now. Worst case scenario, the health insurers will engage in unethical/fraudulent shell games to meet the MLR floor requirement.
Instead of a basic MLR floor, regulators should hold health insurers accountable for measurable quality standards, such as morbidity and mortality. The MLR rule sets a minimum for spending of the premium with medical providers, but, as Robinson (1997) pointed out, “Neither premiums nor expenditures by themselves indicate quality of care.”
Health insurance and healthcare delivery are complicated. In my opinion, the regulating MLR is an over-simplified solution that will not effectively reduce costs or improve quality of our healthcare system. But perhaps that policy horse has already left the barn.